• United Kingdom of Great Britain and Northern Ireland
  • Republic of Ireland
  • UN and the Nordic countries
  • UN-EU Partnership
  • UN Brussels Team
  • Ciné-ONU Geneva
  • Competitions
  • Video Games
  • Mobile Apps
  • Fellowships, Scholarships, Grants and Talent programmes
  • Employment and internships
  • Brussels Vacancies
  • Info-COVID-19
  • UN e-learning courses
  • Backgrounders
  • UN Research Guides
  • Publication List
  • Newsletters, Journals, Bulletins
  • UN Depository Libraries, UN Sales Publications
  • 17 Goals to transform our world
  • ACTNOW Campaign
  • SDG Board Game
  • Cycling for the Global Goals
  • World Cleanup Day

UNRIC.ORG

A-Z Site Index

Green economy: a path towards sustainable development and poverty eradication

Windturbines in a field

Ecology, economy, and equity. Those are the key points in a Green Economy. Those are the pathway to a wealthy and inclusive nation.

For the past few years, the use of term “Green Economy” has increased and has e.g. been used by the UN, heads of state, the EU, and OECD to explain the nexus between sustainability, economics and the environment. In fact, a transition towards a Green Economy is exactly what is needed to achieve multiple Sustainable Development Goals – both goals on climate action, but also on economic growth, justice, and well-being. Creating a sustainable and green economies, more jobs, and a healthy planet for all, where no one is left behind, is the objective of conference Stockholm+50 in June 2022.

What is green economy?

Birds standing on a cliff

A green economy is defined as low carbon, resource efficient and socially inclusive. In a green economy, growth in employment and income are driven by public and private investment into such economic activities, infrastructure and assets that allow reduced carbon emissions and pollution, enhanced energy and resource efficiency, and prevention of the loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services. A green economy means investments in renewable energy, such as solar power, onshore and offshore wind power, hydrogen, electric vehicles, and energy efficient homes.

The notion of green economy does not replace sustainable development, but creates a new focus on the economy, investment, capital and infrastructure, employment and skills and positive social and environmental outcomes.

A green economy is strongly interlinked with SDG 13, Climate Action , but, moreover, it aims attention at life quality with people at the centre.

The four dimensions of green economies

A green economy prioritizes health of the planet and of the people, and regards these as interlinked. Prioritization and implementation of the green initiative also help countries achieve multiple sustainable development goals.

SDG 3: Good health and well-being

Major investments in the energy sector and environmental sector would result in job creation for hundreds of thousands of jobs. The concentration on clean energy and growing wealth all supports the expansion of natural, human, and social capital, thus offering work opportunities for green livelihoods, companies, and organizations. Moreover, the sectorial activities will create potential for training, sustainable infrastructure and education for all people to prosper.

SDG 16: Peace, justice and strong institutions

The green economy and its economic and social advantages are supported by evidence. To get a successful green economy, institutions need to be interdisciplinary – deploying science, economics, knowledge across sectors and local know-how. By including the different aspects of communities, a green economy will build a financial system that serve the interests of society by promoting local economies, while maintaining common standards and procedures.

SDG 13: Climate action

Plastic bottles in a bag

A green recovery safeguards, restores and invests in nature; a crucial detail in green economies is climate mitigation and restoration of biodiversity. Due to the limited sustainability of natural capital, recovery and growth of water, soil and natural systems are a high priority. Furthermore, a green economy is strongly linked with circular economy: a model of production and consumption which involves recycling and reusing materials and products for as long as possible.

SDG 12: Responsible consumption and production

The green economy is interlinked with circular economy. Regarding consumption, there ought to be a shift to reduce consumption of natural resources to sustainable levels. An inclusive economy incorporates and embraces modern models of economic development whose objective is to create prosperity within planetary boundaries.

The United Nations Environmental Programme, UNEP , works with the term Green Economy and encourages implementation of a greener agenda in developing countries. The main areas of their work are focus on green finance, technology and investments, and advocacy of macro-economic approach to sustainable economic growth through regional, sub-regional and national fora. At last, UNEP provides support to countries in terms of development and mainstreaming of macro-economic policies to support the transition to a Green Economy. One of the countries is Kenya.

Kenya: feed-in tariffs

Kenya has one of the most dynamic economies in Africa, yet it is facing a number of pressing economic, environmental and social challenges. From climate change and natural resource depletion to high poverty rates and rising unemployment, the country is addressing these concerns through its commitment to a low-carbon and resource-efficient development pathway.

Nairobi, Kenya

UNEP iterated that government policy has an essential role to play in enhancing incentives for investing in renewable energy. One way of doing this is by enforcing time-bound incentives, subsidies, tax credits, and feed-in tariffs. The latter has been implemented in more than 30 developed countries and in 17 developing countries. Kenya introduced a feed-in tariff on electricity generated from wind, biomass and small hydropower in 2008, and extended the tariffs in 2010 to include geothermal, biogas and solar energy.

As with any kind of positive support, the design of feed-in tariffs is crucial for determining their success, depending on issues such as time periods for support, graduated tariff decreases over time, minimum or maximum capacity limits.

Stockholm+50

These green investments need to be enabled and supported through targeted public expenditure, policy reforms and changes in taxation and regulation.

Stockholm+50

By recognizing the importance of multilateralism in tackling the Earth’s triple planetary crisis – climate, nature, and pollution – the event will act as a springboard accelerate the implementation of the UN Decade of Action to deliver the Sustainable Development Goals, including the 2030 Agenda, and the Paris Agreement on climate change.

To learn more about SDGs, climate mitigation, multilateral cooperation in the environmental sector, see here:

Stockholm+50 .

Sustainable infrastructure to battle climate change (unric.org)

Latest news

Eu priorities at the un general assembly, waste without borders, how the music industry can keep advancing the sdgs, gaza: “the first victim of the war is truth”, ukraine: over 6 million refugees spread across europe.

More from our Engagement Hub

  • Terms of Use
  • Fraud Alert
  • Privacy Notice

Green Economy and Sustainability Essay

  • To find inspiration for your paper and overcome writer’s block
  • As a source of information (ensure proper referencing)
  • As a template for you assignment

Despite the fact that some of the environmental concerns of the 90s were addressed in 2000s, the hype for environmentalism seems to be gaining increasingly more significance. Green economy is often viewed as the alternative to the current approach towards consumption. Traditionally, green economy is defined as the attempt of developing the economic strategy that will allow for a reasonable allocation of natural resources and the practice of sustainability.

Emerging in 1990s and gaining significance in 2000s, the above-mentioned approach is also known as “a range of activities which are dependent on the regions’ natural and historic built environment or which are involved in protecting or improving the environment” (Sydney Olympic Park Authority 9). The concept of sustainability, which is often mentioned as the key building block of green economy, can be interpreted as rational usage of natural resources, both inexhaustible and exhaustible ones.

In regard to the above-mentioned definitions, the issues raised in the interview conducted with a representative of the concerned party, i.e., an “instructor at UCRI” (Lastname, personal communication, 2015), as the respondent called herself, sheds some light on the idea of integrating the basic principles of sustainability into the framework of a company’s operations.

Being interested in the promotion of a sustainable approach in all domains of modern life, the interviewee makes it very clear that her concept of sustainability as the development of industry that may coexist with the environment without altering it drastically. In fact, the interviewee has raised a very peculiar point concerning the definition of sustainability by saying that coming up with one is rather hard due to the numerous factors involved.

In other words, the interview with the person in question prompts the idea that the definition for the subject matter, in fact, cannot be coined at all. The above-mentioned remark leads to a rather dark supposition concerning the impossibility to reach the level of sustainable development.

In other words, it can be assumed that, no matter how the production process in industries might be improved, negative consequences affecting nature will always remain a problem. Therefore, the interview shows in a rather graphic way that sustainable development cannot be attained in its entirety, yet needs to be strived for.

In addition, the interviewee provides a rather peculiar idea of what entrepreneurships need to do in order to enhance the sustainability based policy in their operations: “We need increased transparency about not only how these things are being conducted, but also, you know, ultimately, at some level I think it comes down to people voting with their wallet and, you know, the cheaper product is always going to win” (Lastname, personal communication, 2015).

Particularly, the interviewee mentions the significance of transparency as the key towards management of modern organizations. Indeed, by keeping a close focus on the key steps that an organization makes, the society is most likely to affect the choices of the organization under analysis, therefore, making it incline towards a more sustainable use of resources.

One must admit, though, that the suggested approach may conflict with the policies concerning the non-disclosure ethics in most organizations; unless the necessity for companies to be transparent is established on a statewide level officially and is acknowledged by the existing legal system, further violations of the environmental ethics are most likely to become a possibility.

The food security, as well as the security of energy and water security, can also be considered very vast topics that need to be addressed separately with the further synthesis of the information acquired in the process.

Indeed, seeing that the issues mentioned above are dependent on a variety of factors, including the social, the economic and the political ones, they do need a separate study: “With all these questions in order for us to develop some sort of like sustainability idea or consumption we have to think about it as a whole ecosystem” (Lastname, personal communication, 2015).

However, the link that exists between them still requires that the outcomes of these studies should be put together in a search for the solution that could accommodate every stakeholder involved. As far as the issue that could connect the three problems in question, the consumption concern needs to be addressed.

As the respondent explains, the increased rates of consumption affect the environment not only as the key cause of natural resources exhaustion, but also the enhancement of industries and, thus, the increase of their negative impact on the environment. Indeed, the current rates of consumerism are beyond admissible; defining the problems that the humankind has to face regarding the lack of resources, the rise in the environmental pollution rates, etc.

Despite the fact that similar concerns were raised several decades ago, a comparatively small progress has been made so far, the current industries still putting a very strong emphasis on the enhancement of their performance rather than on the effects that their operations have on the environment and health issues development. In this regard, it was rather unexpected to hear the respondent omit the concept of green economy and green philosophy in general.

An essential step towards reasonable use of resources, sustainability must be incorporated into the framework of modern organizational along with other tools suggested by the respondent, including green economy. It would be naïve to assume that the introduction of green economy principles will eradicate the current environmental concerns; however, it will provide more avenues for addressing the latter. As long as people realize the significance of the green strategy, new opportunities for improvement will emerge

Works Cited

Sydney Olympic Park Authority 2005, State of Environment Report . 2015. Web.

  • For-Profit Public Companies Challenges
  • Minimum Wages and Its Effects on the Hospitality Industry
  • Cooperative Exporters: The Enhancement of the International Assistance
  • Effectiveness of Interview and Influencing Factors
  • Researching the Genetic Enhancement: Unethical Practice and Social Norms
  • Adam Smith' Economics: Nation's and Citizens Wealth
  • Demand, Supply and Their Interaction on Markets
  • Outsourcing and Its Benefits for US Economy
  • Long Term Investment Decisions
  • Attractive and Unattractive Industries
  • Chicago (A-D)
  • Chicago (N-B)

IvyPanda. (2020, May 6). Green Economy and Sustainability. https://ivypanda.com/essays/green-economy-and-sustainability/

"Green Economy and Sustainability." IvyPanda , 6 May 2020, ivypanda.com/essays/green-economy-and-sustainability/.

IvyPanda . (2020) 'Green Economy and Sustainability'. 6 May.

IvyPanda . 2020. "Green Economy and Sustainability." May 6, 2020. https://ivypanda.com/essays/green-economy-and-sustainability/.

1. IvyPanda . "Green Economy and Sustainability." May 6, 2020. https://ivypanda.com/essays/green-economy-and-sustainability/.

Bibliography

IvyPanda . "Green Economy and Sustainability." May 6, 2020. https://ivypanda.com/essays/green-economy-and-sustainability/.

IvyPanda uses cookies and similar technologies to enhance your experience, enabling functionalities such as:

  • Basic site functions
  • Ensuring secure, safe transactions
  • Secure account login
  • Remembering account, browser, and regional preferences
  • Remembering privacy and security settings
  • Analyzing site traffic and usage
  • Personalized search, content, and recommendations
  • Displaying relevant, targeted ads on and off IvyPanda

Please refer to IvyPanda's Cookies Policy and Privacy Policy for detailed information.

Certain technologies we use are essential for critical functions such as security and site integrity, account authentication, security and privacy preferences, internal site usage and maintenance data, and ensuring the site operates correctly for browsing and transactions.

Cookies and similar technologies are used to enhance your experience by:

  • Remembering general and regional preferences
  • Personalizing content, search, recommendations, and offers

Some functions, such as personalized recommendations, account preferences, or localization, may not work correctly without these technologies. For more details, please refer to IvyPanda's Cookies Policy .

To enable personalized advertising (such as interest-based ads), we may share your data with our marketing and advertising partners using cookies and other technologies. These partners may have their own information collected about you. Turning off the personalized advertising setting won't stop you from seeing IvyPanda ads, but it may make the ads you see less relevant or more repetitive.

Personalized advertising may be considered a "sale" or "sharing" of the information under California and other state privacy laws, and you may have the right to opt out. Turning off personalized advertising allows you to exercise your right to opt out. Learn more in IvyPanda's Cookies Policy and Privacy Policy .

Towards a New, Green Economy

  • November 2016

Peter A. Victor at York University

  • York University

Tim Jackson at Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP)

  • Centre for the Understanding of Sustainable Prosperity (CUSP)

Abstract and Figures

Trends in GDP, Wellbeing and Environment in Canada between 1994 and 2010. Source: Canadian Index of Wellbeing 2012

Discover the world's research

  • 25+ million members
  • 160+ million publication pages
  • 2.3+ billion citations
  • Igor Aleksandrov

Marina Fedorova

  • Recruit researchers
  • Join for free
  • Login Email Tip: Most researchers use their institutional email address as their ResearchGate login Password Forgot password? Keep me logged in Log in or Continue with Google Welcome back! Please log in. Email · Hint Tip: Most researchers use their institutional email address as their ResearchGate login Password Forgot password? Keep me logged in Log in or Continue with Google No account? Sign up
  • Open access
  • Published: 22 June 2020

The green economy transition: the challenges of technological change for sustainability

  • Patrik Söderholm   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0003-2264-7043 1  

Sustainable Earth volume  3 , Article number:  6 ( 2020 ) Cite this article

121k Accesses

154 Citations

66 Altmetric

Metrics details

The Green Economy is an alternative vision for growth and development; one that can generate economic development and improvements in people’s lives in ways consistent with advancing also environmental and social well-being. One significant component of a green economy strategy is to promote the development and adoption of sustainable technologies. The overall objective of this article is to discuss a number of challenges encountered when pursuing sustainable technological change, and that need to be properly understood by policy makers and professionals at different levels in society. We also identify some avenues for future research. The discussions center on five challenges: (a) dealing with diffuse – and ever more global – environmental risks; (b) achieving radical and not just incremental sustainable technological change; (c) green capitalism and the uncertain business-as-usual scenario; (d) the role of the state and designing appropriate policy mixes; and (e) dealing with distributional concerns and impacts. The article argues that sustainable technological change will require a re-assessment of the roles of the private industry and the state, respectively, and that future research should increasingly address the challenges of identifying and implementing novel policy instrument combinations in various institutional contexts.

The green economy transition and sustainable technological change

Over the last decade, a frequent claim has been that the traditional economic models need to be reformed in order to address climate change, biodiversity losses, water scarcity, etc., while at the same time addressing key social and economic challenges. The global financial crisis in 2008–2009 spurred this debate [ 4 ], and these concerns have been translated into the vision of a ‘green economy’ (e.g., [ 31 , 33 , 48 , 54 , 55 ]). Furthermore, in 2015, countries world-wide adopted the so-called 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development and its 17 Sustainable Development Goals. These goals recognize that ending world poverty must go hand-in-hand with strategies that build economic growth but also address a range of various social needs including education, health, social protection, and job creation, while at the same time tackling environmental pollution and climate change. The sustainable development goals thus also establish a real link between the ecological system and the economic system. They also reinforce the need for a transition to a green economy, i.e., a fundamental transformation towards more sustainable modes of production and consumption.

In this article, we focus on a particularly important component of such a transition, namely the development of sustainable technological change, i.e., production and consumption patterns implying profoundly less negative impacts on the natural environment, including the global climate. Specifically, the article addresses a number of key challenges in supporting – and overcoming barriers to – sustainable technological change. These challenges are presented with the ambition to communicate important lessons from academic research to policy makers and professionals as well as the general public.

Addressing climate and environmental challenges, clearly requires natural scientific knowledge as well as engineering expertise concerning the various technical solutions that can be adopted to mitigate the negative impacts (e.g., carbon-free energy technologies). However, pursuing sustainable technological change is also a societal, organizational, political, and economic endeavor that involves several non-technical challenges. For instance, the so-called transitions literature recognizes that many sectors, such as energy generation, water supply etc., can be conceptualized as socio-technical systems and/or innovation systems [ 24 , 40 ]. These systems consist of networks of actors (individuals, private firms, research institutes, government authorities, etc.), the knowledge that these actors possess as well as the relevant institutions (legal rules, codes of conduct, etc.). In other words, the development of, for instance, new carbon-free technologies may often require the establishment of new value chains hosting actors that have not necessarily interacted in the past; this necessitates a relatively long process that can alter society in several ways, e.g., through legal amendments, changed consumer behavior, distributional effects, infrastructure development and novel business models.

In other words, beyond technological progress, economic and societal adjustment is necessary to achieve sustainable technological change. In fact, history is full of examples that illustrate the need to address the organizational and institutional challenges associated with technological change and innovation. In hindsight, the societal impacts of electricity in terms of productivity gains were tremendous during the twentieth century. Still, while electrical energy was discovered in the late 1870s, in the year 1900, less than 5% of mechanical power in American factories was supplied by electric motors and it took yet another 20 years before their productivity soared [ 14 ]. An important reason for the slow diffusion of electric power was that in order to take full advantage of the new technology, existing factories had to change the entire systems of operation, i.e., the production process, the architecture, the logistics as well as the ways in which workers were recruited, trained and paid. Footnote 1 A similar story emerges when considering the impact of computers on total productivity during the second half of the twentieth century. For long, many companies invested in computers for little or no reward. Also in this case, however, the new technology required systemic changes in order for companies to be able to take advantage of the computer. This meant, for instance, decentralizing, outsourcing, and streamlining supply chains as well as offering more choices to consumers [ 9 ].

This key argument that the adoption of new technology has to be accompanied by systemic changes, applies both to the company as well as the societal level. Any novel solutions being developed must take into account the complexity of the interdependencies between different types of actors with various backgrounds, overall market dynamics, as well as the need for knowledge development and institutional reforms. In fact, the need for systemic changes may be particularly relevant in the case of green technologies, such as zero-carbon processes in the energy-intensive industries (see further below).

Against this background, the issue of how to promote sustainable technological change has received increasing attention in the policy arena and in academic research. The main objective of this article is therefore to discuss some of the most significant societal challenges in pursuing such change, and outline key insights for policy makers as well as important avenues for future research. In doing this, we draw on several strands of the academic literature. The article centers on the following five overall challenges:

Dealing with diffuse – and ever more global – environmental risks

Achieving radical – and not just incremental – sustainable technological change;

The advent of green capitalism: the uncertain business-as-usual scenario

The role of the state: designing appropriate policy mixes, dealing with distributional concerns and impacts.

The first two challenges address the various types of structural tasks that are required to pursue sustainable technological change, and the barriers that have to be overcome when pursuing these tasks. The remaining points concern the role and the responsibility of different key actors in the transition process, not least private firms and government authorities. Each of these five challenges in turn involves more specific challenges, and these are identified and elaborated under each heading. We also provide hints about how to address and manage these challenges, but specific solutions will likely differ depending on the national or regional contexts. The paper concludes by briefly outlining some key avenues for future research, and with an emphasis on research that can assist a green socio-technical transition. Footnote 2

With the advent of modern environmental policy in the 1960s, stringent regulations were imposed on emissions into air and water. However, the focus was more or less exclusively on stationary pollution sources (i.e., industrial plants), which were relatively easy to monitor and regulate, e.g., through plant-specific emission standards. In addition, during this early era there was a strong emphasis on local environmental impacts, e.g., emissions into nearby river basins causing negative effects on other industries and/or on households in the same community.

Over the years, though, the environmental challenges have increasingly been about targeting various types of diffuse emissions. These stem from scattered sources such as road transport, shipping, aviation, and agriculture. Pollution from diffuse sources takes place over large areas and individually they may not be of concern, but in combination with other diffuse sources they can cause serious overall impacts. The growing importance of global environmental challenges such as climate change in combination with globalization and more international trade in consumer products, adds to this challenge. Managing these issues often requires international negotiations and burden-sharing, which in itself have proved difficult [ 12 ]. The difficulties in reaching a stringent-enough global climate agreement illustrate this difficulty.

Diffuse emissions are typically difficult to monitor and therefore also to regulate. For instance, environmental authorities may wish to penalize improper disposal of a waste product since this would help reduce various chemical risks, but such behavior is typically clandestine and difficult to detect. Plastic waste is an apt example; it stems from millions of consumer products, is carried around the world by the currents and winds, and builds up microplastics, particularly in the sea. Many dangerous substances, including chemicals such as solvents and phthalates, are embedded in consumer products, out of which many are imported. Monitoring the potential spread of these substances to humans and the natural environment remains difficult as well. Technological innovation that permits better tracing and tracking of materials should therefore be a priority (see also [ 21 ]).

In order to address these diffuse environmental impacts, society has to find alternative – yet more indirect – ways of monitoring and regulating them. This could translate into attempts to close material cycles and promote a circular economy, i.e., an economy in which the value of products, materials and resources are maintained as long as possible [ 19 ]. In practice, this implies an increased focus on reduction, recycling and re-use of virgin materials [ 30 ], material and energy efficiency, as well as sharing of resources (often with the help of various digital platforms such as Uber and Airbnb). In other words, rather than regulating emissions as close to damage done as possible, the authorities may instead support specific activities (e.g., material recycling) and/or technologies (e.g., low-carbon production processes) that can be assumed to correlate with reduced environmental load.

Addressing diffuse emissions in such indirect ways, though, is not straightforward. In several countries, national waste management strategies adhere to the so-called waste hierarchy (see also the EU Waste Framework Directive). This sets priorities for which types of action should be taken, and postulates that waste prevention should be given the highest priority followed by re-use of waste, material recycling, recovery of waste and landfill (in that order). Even though research has shown that this hierarchy is a reasonable rule of thumb from an environmental point of view [ 42 ], it is only a rule of thumb! Deviations from the hierarchy can be motivated in several cases and must therefore be considered (e.g., [ 58 ]). Footnote 3

One important way of encouraging recycling and reuse of products is to support product designs that factor in the reparability and reusability of products. Improved recyclability can also benefit from a modular product structure (e.g., [ 20 ]). However, this also comes with challenges. Often companies manufacture products in such ways that increase the costs of recycling for downstream processors, but for institutional reasons, there may be no means by which the waste recovery facility can provide the manufacturer with any incentives to change the product design [ 11 , 46 ]. One example is the use of multi-layer plastics for food packaging, which could often be incompatible with mechanical recycling.

While the promotion of material and energy efficiency measures also can be used to address the problem of diffuse environmental impacts, it may be a mixed blessing. Such measures imply that the economy can produce the same amount of goods and services but with less material and energy inputs, but they also lead to a so-called rebound effect [ 27 ]. Along with productivity improvements, resources are freed and can be used to increase the production and consumption of other goods. In other words, the efficiency gains may at least partially be cancelled out by increased consumption elsewhere in the economy. For instance, if consumers choose to buy fuel-efficient cars, they are able to travel more or spend the money saved by lower fuel use on other products, which in turn will exploit resources and lead to emissions.

Finally, an increased focus on circular economy solutions will imply that the different sectors of the economy need to become more interdependent. This interdependency is indeed what makes the sought-after efficiency gains possible in the first place. This in turn requires new forms of collaborative models among companies, including novel business models. In some cases, though, this may be difficult to achieve. One example is the use of excess heat from various process industries; it can be employed for supplying energy to residential heating or greenhouses. Such bilateral energy cooperation is already quite common (e.g., in Sweden), but pushing this even further may be hard and/or too costly. Investments in such cooperation are relation-specific [ 60 ], i.e., their returns will depend on the continuation of the relationships. The involved companies may be too heterogeneous in terms of goals, business practices, planning horizons etc., therefore making long-term commitment difficult. Moreover, the excess heat is in an economic sense a byproduct, implying that its supply will be constrained by the production of the main product. Of course, this is valid for many other types of waste products as well, e.g., manure digested to generate biogas, secondary aluminum from scrapped cars.

In brief, the growing importance of addressing diffuse emissions into the natural environment implies that environmental protection has to build on indirect pollution abatement strategies. Pursuing each of these strategies (e.g., promoting recycling and material efficiency), though, imply challenges; they may face important barriers (e.g., for product design, and byproduct use) and could have negative side-effects (e.g., rebound effects). Moreover, a focus on recycling and resource efficiency must not distract from the need to improve the tracing and tracking of hazardous substances and materials as well as provide stronger incentives for product design. Both technological and organizational innovations are needed.

Achieving radical – and not just incremental – sustainable technological change

Incremental innovations, e.g., increased material and energy efficiency in existing production processes, are key elements for the transition to a green economy. However, more profound – and even radical – technological innovation is also needed. For instance, replacing fossil fuels in the transport sector as well as in iron and steel production requires fundamental technological shifts and not just incremental efficiency improvements (e.g., [ 1 ]). There are, however, a number of factors that will make radical innovation inherently difficult. Below, we highlight three important obstacles.

First , one obstacle is the risk facing firms that invest in technological development (e.g., basic R&D, pilot tests etc.) in combination with the limited ability of the capital market to handle the issue of long-term risk-taking. These markets may fail to provide risk management instruments for immature technology due to a lack of historical data to assess risks. There are also concerns that the deregulation of the global financial markets has implied that private financial investors take a more short-term view [ 44 ]. In fact, research also suggests that due to agency problems within private firms, their decision-making may be biased towards short-term payoffs, thus resulting in myopic behavior also in the presence of fully efficient capital markets [ 53 ].

Second , private investors may often have weak incentives to pursue investments in long-term technological development. The economics literature has noted the risks for the under-provision of public goods such as the knowledge generated from R&D efforts and learning-by-doing (e.g., [ 38 ]). Thus, private companies will be able to appropriate only a fraction of the total rate-of-return on such investment, this since large benefits will also accrue to other companies (e.g., through reverse engineering). Due to the presence of such knowledge spillovers, investments in long-term technological development will become inefficient and too modest.

Third , new green technologies often face unfair competition with incumbent technologies. The incumbents, which may be close substitutes to their greener competitors, will be at a relative competitive advantage since they have been allowed to expand during periods of less stringent environmental policies as well as more or less tailor-made institutions and infrastructures. This creates path-dependencies, i.e. where the economy tends to be locked-in to certain technological pathways [ 2 ]. In general, companies typically employ accumulated technology-specific knowledge when developing new products and processes, and technology choices tend to be particularly self-reinforcing if the investments are characterized by high upfront costs and increasing returns from adoption (such as scale, learning and network economies). Existing institutions, e.g., laws, codes of conduct, etc., could also contribute to path dependence since these often favor the incumbent (e.g., fossil-fuel based) technologies [ 57 ].

The above three factors tend to inhibit all sorts of long-run technological development in the private sector, but there is reason to believe that they could be particularly troublesome in the case of green technologies. First, empirical research suggests that green technologies (e.g., in energy and transport) generate large knowledge spillovers than the dirtier technologies they replace [ 15 , 49 ]. Moreover, while the protection of property rights represents one way to limit such spillovers, the patenting system is subject to limitations. For instance, Neuhoff [ 43 ] remarks that many sustainable technologies:

“consist of a large set of components and require the expertise of several firms to improve the system. A consortium will face difficulties in sharing the costs of ‘learning investment’, as it is difficult to negotiate and fix the allocation of future profits,” (p. 98).

These are generally not favorable conditions for effective patenting. Process innovations, e.g., in industry, are particularly important for sustainable technology development, but firms are often more likely to employ patents to protect new products rather than new processes [ 39 ]. Footnote 4

Furthermore, one of the key socio-technical systems in the green economy transition, the energy system, is still today dominated by incumbent technologies such as nuclear energy and fossil-fueled power, and exhibits several characteristics that will lead to path dependent behavior. Investments are often large-scale and exhibit increasing returns. Path dependencies are also aggravated by the fact that the outputs from different energy sources – and regardless of environmental performance – are more or less perfect substitutes. In other words, the emerging and carbon-free technologies can only compete on price with the incumbents, and they therefore offer little scope for product differentiation. In addition, the energy sectors are typically highly regulated, thus implying that existing technological patterns are embedded in and enforced by a complex set of institutions as well as infrastructure.

In brief, technological change for sustainability requires more radical technological shifts, and such shifts are characterized by long and risky development periods during which new systemic structures – i.e., actor networks, value chains, knowledge, and institutions – need to be put in place and aligned with the emerging technologies. Overall, the private sector cannot alone be expected to generate these structures, and for this reason, some kind of policy support is needed. Nevertheless, in order for any policy instrument or policy mix to be efficient, it has to build on a proper understanding of the underlying obstacles for long-run technological development. As different technologies tend to face context-specific learning processes, patenting prospects, risk profiles etc., technology-specific support may be needed (see also below).

At least since the advent of the modern environmental debate during the 1960s, economic and environmental goals have been perceived to be in conflict with each other. Business decisions, it has been argued, build on pursuing profit-maximization; attempts to address environmental concerns simultaneously will therefore imply lower profits and reduced productivity. However, along with increased concerns about the environmental footprints of the global economy and the growth of organic products and labels, material waste recycling, climate compensation schemes etc., sustainability issues have begun to move into the mainstream business activities. In fact, many large companies often no longer distinguish between environmental innovation and innovation in general; the environmental footprints of the business operations are almost always taken into consideration during the innovation process (e.g., [ 47 ]).

Some even puts this in Schumpeterian terms, and argues that sustainable technological change implies a “new wave of creative destruction with the potential to change fundamentally the competitive dynamics in many markets and industries,” ([ 37 ], p. 315). The literature has recognized the potentially important roles that so-called sustainability entrepreneurs can play in bringing about a shift to a green economy; these types of entrepreneurs seek to combine traditional business practices with sustainable development initiatives (e.g., [ 25 ]). They could disrupt established business models, cultures and consumer preferences, as well as help reshape existing institutions. Just as conventional entrepreneurs, they are agents of change and offer lessons for policy makers. However, the research in this field has also been criticized for providing a too strong focus on individual success stories, while, for instance, the institutional and political factors that are deemed to also shape the priorities made by these individuals tend to be neglected (e.g., [ 13 ]).

Ultimately, it remains very difficult to anticipate how far voluntary, market-driven initiatives will take us along the long and winding road to the green economy. In addition to a range of incremental developments, such as increased energy and material efficiency following the adoption of increased digitalization, industrial firms and sustainability entrepreneurs are likely to help develop new and/or refined business models (e.g., to allow for increased sharing and recycling of resources) as well as adopt innovations commercially. In the future, businesses are also likely to devote greater attention to avoiding future environmental liabilities, such as the potential costs of contaminated land clean-up or flood risks following climate change. Far from surprising, large insurance companies were among the first to view climate change as a risk to their viability. One response was the development of new financial instruments such as ‘weather derivatives’ and ‘catastrophe bonds’ [ 35 ].

In other words, there is an increasing demand for businesses that work across two logics that in the past have been perceived as incompatible: the commercial and the environmental. There are however huge uncertainties about the scope and the depth of green capitalism in this respect. Moreover, the answer to the question of how far the market-driven sustainability transition will take us, will probably vary depending on business sector and on factors such as the availability of funding in these sectors. Footnote 5

As indicated above, there are reasons to assume that in the absence of direct policy support, businesses will not be well-equipped to invest in long-term green technology development. Green product innovations may often be easier to develop and nurture since firms then may charge price premiums to consumers. In fact, many high-profile sustainability entrepreneurs in the world (e.g., Anita Roddick of The Body Shop) have been product innovators. In contrast, green process innovation is more difficult to pursue. It is hard to get consumers to pay premiums for such innovations. For instance, major efforts are needed to develop a carbon-free blast furnace process in modern iron and steel plants (e.g., [ 1 ]). And even if this is achieved, it remains unclear whether the consumers will be willing to pay a price premium on their car purchases purely based on the knowledge that the underlying production process is less carbon-intense than it used to be. Moreover, taking results from basic R&D, which appear promising on the laboratory scale, through “the valley of death” into commercial application is a long and risky journey. Process innovations typically require gradual up-scaling and optimization of the production technologies (e.g., [ 29 ]). For small- and medium-sized firms in particular, this may be a major hurdle.

In brief, the above suggests that it is difficult to anticipate what a baseline scenario of the global economy – i.e., a scenario involving no new policies – would look like from a sustainability perspective. Still, overall it is likely that green capitalism and sustainability entrepreneurship alone may have problems delivering the green economy transition in (at least) two respects. First, due to the presence of knowledge spillovers and the need for long-term risk-taking, the baseline scenario may involve too few radical technology shifts (e.g., in process industries). Second, the baseline scenario is very likely to involve plenty of digitalization and automation, in turn considerably increasing the potential for material and energy efficiency increases. Nevertheless, due to rebound effects, the efficiency gains resulting from new technologies alone may likely not be enough to address the sustainability challenge. This therefore also opens up the field for additional policy support, and – potentially – a rethinking of the role of the state in promoting sustainable technological change.

An important task for government policy is to set the appropriate “framework conditions” for the economy. This refers primarily to the legal framework, e.g., immaterial rights, licensing procedures, as well as contract law, which need to be predictable and transparent. Traditional environmental policy that regulates emissions either through taxes or performance standards will remain important, as will the removal of environmentally harmful subsidies (where such exist). The role of such policies is to make sure that the external costs of environmental pollution are internalized in firms’ and households’ decision-making (e.g., [ 7 ]). Still, in the light of the challenges discussed above – i.e., controlling diffuse emissions, the need for more fundamental sustainable technological change, as well as the private sector’s inability to adequately tackle these two challenges – the role of the state must often go beyond providing such framework conditions. In fact, there are several arguments for implementing a broader mix of policy instruments in the green economy.

In the waste management field, policy mixes may be needed for several reasons. For instance, previous research shows that in cases where diffuse emissions cannot be directly controlled and monitored, a combined output tax and recycling subsidy (equivalent to a deposit-refund system) can be an efficient second-best policy instrument mix (e.g., [ 59 ]). This would reduce the amount of materials entering the waste stream, while the subsidy encourages substitution of recycled materials for virgin materials. Footnote 6 An extended waste management policy mix could also be motivated by the limited incentives for manufacturers of products to consider product design and recyclability, which would decrease the costs of downstream recycling by other firms. This is, though, an issue that often cannot be addressed by traditional policies such as taxes and standards; it should benefit from technological and organizational innovation. Finally, the establishment of efficient markets for recycled materials can also be hampered by different types of information-related obstacles, including byers’ inability to assess the quality of mixed waste streams. In such a case, information-based policies based on, for instance, screening requirements at the waste sites could be implemented (e.g., [ 46 ]).

At a general level, fostering green technological development, not least radical innovation, must also build on a mix of policies. The literature has proposed an innovation policy mix based on three broad categories of instruments (see also [ 36 , 51 , 52 ]):

Technology-push instruments that support the provision of basic and applied knowledge inputs, e.g., through R&D grants, patent protection, tax breaks etc.

Demand-pull instruments that encourage the formation of new markets, e.g., through deployment policies such as public procurement, feed-in tariffs, quotas, etc.

Systemic instruments that support various functions operating at the innovation system level, such as providing infrastructure, facilitating alignment among stakeholders, and stimulating the development of goals and various organizational solutions.

A key role for a green innovation policy is to support the development of generic technologies that entrepreneurial firms can build upon [ 50 ]. Public R&D support and co-funding of pilot and demonstration plants help create variation and permit new inventions to be verified, optimized and up-scaled. As noted above, there is empirical support for public R&D funding of green technology development, as underinvestment due to knowledge spillovers might be particularly high for these technologies.

As the technology matures, though, it must be tested in a (niche) market with real customers, and the state will often have to create the conditions for private firms to raise long-term funding in areas where established financial organizations are not yet willing to provide sufficient funds. For instance, in the renewable energy field, this has been achieved by introducing feed-in tariffs or quota schemes for, for instance, wind power and solar PV technology (e.g., [ 16 ]). Finally, well-designed systemic instruments will have positive impacts on the functioning of the other instruments in the policy mix; while technology-push and demand-pull instruments are the engines of the innovation policy mix, the systemic instruments will help that engine run faster and more efficiently.

The implementation of the above policy mixes will be associated with several challenges, such as gaining political acceptability, identifying the specific designs of the policy instruments, and determining how these instruments can be evaluated. All these issues deserve attention in future research. Still, here we highlight in particular the need for policies that are technology-specific; i.e., in contrast to, for instance, pollution taxes or generic R&D subsidies they promote selected technological fields and/or sectors. Based on the above discussions one can point out two motives for relying on technology-specific instruments in promoting sustainable technological change: (a) the regulations of diffuse emissions can often not target diffuse emissions directly – at least not without incurring excessively high monitoring costs; and (b) the need to promote more radical environmental innovations.

The innovation systems surrounding green energy technology tend to be technology-specific. Different technologies are exposed to unique and multi-dimensional growth processes, e.g., in terms of bottlenecks, learning processes, and the dynamics of the capital goods industries [ 34 ]. The nature of the knowledge spillovers and the long-term risks will also differ as will the likelihood that green technologies suffer from technological lock-in associated with incumbent technology (e.g., [ 38 ]). For instance, the technological development process for wind power has been driven by turbine manufacturers and strong home markets, while equipment suppliers and manufacturers that own their own equipment have dominated solar PV development [ 32 ].

Clearly, technology-specific policies are difficult to design and implement; regulators typically face significant information constraints and their decisions may also be influenced by politico-economic considerations such as bureaucratic motives, and lobby group interests. Moreover, the prospects for efficient green technology-specific policies may likely also differ across jurisdictions; some countries will be more likely to be able to implement policies that can live up to key governing principles such as accountability, discipline and building on arms-length interactions with the private sector. As noted by Rodrik [ 50 ], “government agencies need to be embedded in, but not in bed with, business,” (p. 485).

The above begs the question whether the governance processes at the national and the supra-national levels (e.g., the EU) are in place to live up to a more proactive and transformative role for the state. Newell and Paterson [ 45 ] argue that such a state needs to balance two principles that have for long been seen as opposed to one another. These are, one the one hand, the empowerment of the state to actively determine priorities and, on the other, “providing citizens with more extensive opportunities to have a voice, to get more involved in decision-making processes, and to take on a more active role in politics,” (p. 209). The latter issue is further addressed also in the next section.

In brief, the climate and environmental challenges facing society today require a mix of policy instruments, not least because the barriers facing new sustainable technology are multi-faceted and often heterogeneous across technologies. Supporting green innovation should build on the use of technology-specific policies as complements to traditional environmental policies. This in itself poses a challenge to policy-making, and requires in-depth understanding of how various policy instruments interact as well as increased knowledge about the institutional contexts in which these instruments are implemented.

The transition to a green economy, including technological change, affects the whole of society. It is therefore necessary to not only optimize the performance of the new technologies and identify efficient policies; the most significant distributional impacts of technological change must also be understood and addressed. All societal changes involve winners and losers, and unless this is recognized and dealt with, the sought-after green transition may lack in legitimacy across various key groups in society. Bek et al. [ 6 ] provide an example of a green economy initiative in South Africa – the so-called Working for Water (WfW) program – that has failed to fully recognize the social aspects of the program goals.

This challenge concerns different dimensions of distributional impacts. One such dimension is how households with different income levels are affected. Economics research has shown that environmental policies in developed countries, not least taxes on pollution and energy use, tend to have regressive effects [ 22 ], thus implying that the lowest-income households are generally most negatively affected in relative terms. Such outcomes may in fact prevail also in the presence of policies that build on direct support to certain technological pathways. For instance, high-income households are likely to benefit the most from subsidies to solar cells and electric cars, this since these households are more likely to own their own house as well as to be more frequent car buyers. Of course, technological change (e.g., digitalization, automation etc.), including that taking place in green technology, may also have profound distributional impacts in more indirect ways, not the least through its impacts on the labor market (e.g., wages. Work conditions) (e.g., [ 3 ]).

The regional dimension of sustainable development is also important (e.g., [ 26 ]). One challenge in this case is that people increasingly expect that any green investments taking place in their own community (e.g., in wind power) should promote regional growth, employment and various social goals. The increased emphasis on the distributional effects at the regional level can also be attributed to the growing assertion of the rights of people (e.g., indigenous rights), and increased demands for direct participation in the relevant decision-making processes. However, new green technology may fail to generate substantial positive income and employment impacts at the local and regional level. For instance, one factor altering the renewable energy sector’s relationship with the economy has been technological change. A combination of scale economies and increased capital intensity has profoundly increased the investment capital requirements of facilities such as wind mill parks and biofuel production facilities. The inputs into modern green energy projects increasingly also have to satisfy high standards in terms of know-how, and these can therefore not always be supplied by local firms (e.g., [ 18 ]). Indeed, with the implementation of digital technology, the monitoring of, say, entire wind farms can today be done by skilled labor residing in other parts of the country (or even abroad).

Ignoring the distributional effects of sustainable technological change creates social tensions, thereby increasing the business risks for companies and sustainability entrepreneurs. Such risks may come in many forms. For instance, reliability in supply has become increasingly important, and customers will generally not be very forgiving in the presence of disruptions following the emergence of tense community relations. Furthermore, customers, fund managers, banks and prospective employees do not only care about the industry’s output, but increasingly also about how the products have been produced.

In fact, while the economies of the world are becoming more integrated, political trends are pointing towards a stronger focus on the nation state and even on regional independence. If anything, this will further complicate the green economy transition. Specifically, it will need to recognize the difficult trade-offs between efficiency, which typically do require international coordination (e.g., in terms of policy design, and R&D cooperation), and a fair distribution of benefits and costs, which instead tends to demand a stronger regional and local perspective.

In brief, the various distributional effects of sustainable technological change deserve increased attention in both scholarly research and the policy domain in order to ensure that this change emerges in ways that can help reduce poverty and ensure equity. These effects may call for an even broader palette of policies (e.g., benefit-sharing instruments, such as regional or local natural resource funds, compensation schemes, or earmarked tax revenues), but they also call for difficult compromises between efficiency and fairness.

Conclusions and avenues for future research

The scope and the nature the societal challenges that arise as a consequence of the climate and environmental hazards are complex and multi-faceted, and in this article we have focused on five important challenges to sustainable technological change. These challenges are generic, and should be a concern for most countries and regions, even though the specific solutions may differ depending on context. In this final section, we conclude by briefly discussing a number of implications and avenues for future research endeavors. Footnote 7 These knowledge gaps may provide important insights for both the research community as well as for policy makers and officials.

It should be clear that understanding the nature of – as well as managing – socio-technical transitions represents a multi-disciplinary research undertaking. Collaborations between natural scientists and engineers on the one hand and social scientists on the other are of course needed to translate environmental and technical challenges into societal challenges and action. In such collaborative efforts, however, it needs to be recognized that technological change is not a linear process; it entails phases such as concept development, pilot and demonstration projects, market formation and diffusion of technology, but also with important iterations (i.e., feedback loops) among all of these phases. It should be considered how bridges between different technical and social science disciplines can be built, this in order to gain a more in-depth understanding of how technology-specific engineering inventions can be commercialized in various institutional contexts. Transition studies, innovation and environmental economics, as well the innovation system and the innovation management literatures, among others, could help provide such bridges. Other types of systems studies, e.g., energy system optimization modeling, will also be important.

In addition to the above, there should also be an expanded role for cross-fertilization among different social sciences, e.g., between the economics, management and political science fields and between the research on sustainability entrepreneurs and transition studies (see also [ 26 ]). This could help improve the micro-foundations of, for instance, innovation system studies, i.e., better understanding of companies’ incentives, drivers etc., but also stress the need for considering socio-technical systems in the management research. For instance, the focus on individual heroes that pervades much of the entrepreneurship literature may lead to a neglect of the multiple factors at work and the role of framework conditions such as institutions (e.g., legal rules, norms) and infrastructure at the national and local scales. Better integration of various conceptual perspectives on green business and innovation could generate less uncertain business-as-usual scenarios.

The discussions in this article also suggest that green innovation in the public sector should be devoted more attention in future research. This could, of course, focus on various institutional and organizational innovations in the form of new and/or revised policy instrument design. The challenges involved in designing and implementing technology-specific sustainability policies, typically referred to as green industrial policies [ 50 ], tend to require such innovation (e.g., to increase transparency, and avoid regulatory capture). These policies are essentially processes of discovery, both by the state and the industry, rather than a list of specific policy instruments. This implies learning continuously about where the constraints and opportunities lie, and then responding to these.

The risk associated with regulatory capture is one issue that deserves increased attention in future research, including how to overcome such risks. Comparisons of green industrial policies across countries and technological fields – as well as historical comparative studies – could prove useful (e.g., [ 8 ]). How different policies interact as well as what the appropriate level of decision-making power is, are also important questions to be addressed. Of course, given the context-specificity of these types of policies, such research must also address the issue of how transferable innovation and sustainable practices are from one socio-technical and political context to another.

Moreover, the growing importance of diffuse emissions also requires green innovation in the public sector. Specifically, implementing environmental regulations that are close to damages demand specific monitoring technologies that can measure pollution levels. The development of new technologies – which, for instance, facilitates cheap monitoring of emissions – ought to be promoted, but it is quite unclear who has the incentive to promote and undertake such R&D activities. Similar concerns can be raised about the innovations that permit consumers to better assess the environmental footprints of different products and services (e.g., [ 21 ]). Private firms cannot be expected to pursue these types of green innovations intensively. Nevertheless, governments often spend substantial amounts on funding R&D on pollution abatement technology, but less frequently we view government programs funding research on technologies that can facilitate policy enforcement and environmental monitoring.

Finally, the green economy transition should also benefit from research that involves various impact evaluations, including methodological innovation in evaluation studies. This concerns evaluations of the impacts of important baseline trends, e.g., digitalization and automation, globalization versus nationalization, etc., on environmental and distributional outcomes but also on the prospects for green innovation collaborations and various circular economy-inspired business models. Such evaluations could be particularly relevant for understanding possible future pathways for the greening – and de-carbonization – of key process industries. Clearly, there is also need for improved evaluations of policy instruments and combinations of policies. With an increased emphasis on the role of technology-specific policies, such evaluations are far from straightforward. They must consider the different policies’ roles in the innovation systems, and address important interaction effects; any evaluation must also acknowledge the policy learning taking place over time.

Availability of data and materials

Not applicable.

For instance, in the new system, workers had more autonomy and flexibility (e.g., [ 28 ]).

Clearly, given the focus on sustainable technological change, this article does not address all dimensions of the transition to a green economy. Heshmati [ 31 ] provides a recent review of the green economy concept, its theoretical foundations, political background and developmental strategies towards sustainable development. See also Megwai et al. [ 41 ] for an account of various green economy initiatives with a specific focus on developing countries, and Bartelmus [ 5 ] for a critical discussion of the link between the green economy and sustainable development.

For instance, it is typically less negative for the environment to landfill a substantial share of mining waste such as hard rock compared to recycling. Hard rock typically causes little environmental damage, except aesthetically, unless such waste interacts with surface or ground water [ 17 ].

In fact, patents protecting intellectual property rights could even slow down the diffusion of green technologies offering deep emission reductions by creating a bias towards development of close-to-commercial technologies. For instance, Budish et al. [ 10 ] shows that while patents award innovating companies a certain period of market exclusivity, the effective time period may be much shorter since some companies choose to file patents at the time of discovery rather than at first sale. One consequence of this is that the patent system may provide weak incentives for companies to engage in knowledge generation and learning about technologies that face a long time between invention and commercialization.

The UNFCCC [ 56 ] reports substantial increases in climate-related global finance flows, but these flows are still relatively small in the context of wider trends in global investment. They are even judged to be insufficient to meet the additional financing needs required for adaptation to the climate change that cannot be avoided.

If the tax is assessed per pound of intermediate material produced, it will also give producers the incentive to supply lighter-weight products.

See also Future Earth [ 23 ] for a comprehensive list of priorities for a global research sustainability agenda.

Åhman M, Nilsson LJ, Johansson B. Global climate policy and deep de-carbonization of energy-intensive industries. Clim Pol. 2017;17(5):634–49.

Google Scholar  

Arthur WB. Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical small events. Econ J. 1989;99:116–31.

Avent R. The wealth of humans: work, power, and status in the twenty-first century. London: St. Martin’s Press; 2016.

Barbier E. How is the global green new deal going? Nature. 2010;464:832–3.

CAS   Google Scholar  

Bartelmus P. The future we want: green growth or sustainable development? Environ Dev. 2013;7:165–70.

Bek D, Nel E, Binns T. Jobs, water or conservation? Deconstructing the green economy in South Africa’s working for water programme. Environ Dev. 2017;24:136–45.

Bennear LS, Stavins RN. Second-best theory and the use of multiple policy instruments. Environ Resour Econ. 2007;37:111–29.

Bergquist AK, Söderholm K, Kinneryd H, Lindmark M, Söderholm P. Command-and-control revisited: environmental compliance and technological change in Swedish industry 1970–1990. Ecol Econ. 2013;85:6–19.

Brynjolfsson E, Hitt LM. Computation: information technology, organizational trans-formation and business performance. J Econ Perspect. 2000;14:23–48.

Budish E, Roin BN, Williams H. Do firms underinvest in long-term research? Evidence from cancer clinical trials. Am Econ Rev. 2015;105(7):2044–85.

Calcott P, Walls M. Waste, recycling, and ‘design for environment’: roles for markets and policy instruments. Resour Energy Econ. 2005;27(4):287–305.

Ciscar J-C, Saveyn B, Soria A, Szabo L, Van Regemorter D, Van Ierland T. A comparability analysis of global burden sharing GHG reduction scenarios. Energy Policy. 2013;55:73–81.

Cohen B. Sustainable valley entrepreneurial ecosystems. Bus Strateg Environ. 2006;15(1):1–14.

David P. The computer and the dynamo: an historical perspective. Am Econ Rev. 1990;80:355–61.

Dechezleprêtre A, Glachant M, Mohnen M. Knowledge spillovers from clean and dirty technologies: a patent citation analysis. Working paper no. 135. London: Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment; 2017.

Del Rio P, Bleda M. Comparing the innovation effects of support schemes for renewable electricity technologies: a function of innovation approach. Energy Policy. 2012;50:272–82.

Eggert RG, editor. Mining and the environment: international perspectives on public policy. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future; 1994.

Ejdemo T, Söderholm P. Wind power, regional development and benefit-sharing: the case of northern Sweden. Renew Sust Energ Rev. 2015;47:476–85.

European Commission. Closing the loop – an EU action plan for the circular economy. Brussels: COM (2015) 614 final; 2015.

European Environment Agency (EEA). Circular by design. Copenhagen: Products in the Circular Economy; 2017.

Federal Ministry of Education and Research. Green economy research agenda. Bonn: German Government; 2015.

Fullerton D. Six distributional effects of environmental policy. CESifo working paper 3299. Germany: Ifo Institute – Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the University of Munich; 2010.

Future Earth. Strategic research agenda 2014. Priorities for a global sustainability research strategy. Paris: International Council for Science (ICSU); 2014.

Geels FW. From sectoral systems of innovation to socio-technical systems: insights about dynamics and change from sociology and institutional theory. Res Policy. 2004;33:897–920.

Gibbs D. Sustainability entrepreneurs, Ecopreneurs and the development of a sustainable economy. Greener Manag Int. 2009;51:63–78.

Gibbs D, O’Neill K. Future green economies and regional development: a research agenda. Reg Stud. 2017;51(1):161–73.

Greening LA, Greene DL, Difiglio C. Energy efficiency and consumption – the rebound effect – a survey. Energy Policy. 2000;28(6–7):389–401.

Harford T. Fifty things that made the modern economy. London: Little, Brown; 2017.

Hellsmark H, Frishammar J, Söderholm P, Ylinenpää H. The role of pilot and demonstration plants in technology development and innovation policy. Res Policy. 2016;45:1743–61.

Heshmati A. A review of the circular economy and its implementation. Int J Green Econ. 2017;11(3/4):251–88.

Heshmati A. An empirical survey of the ramifications of a green economy. Int J Green Econ. 2018;12(1):53–85.

Huenteler J, Schmidt T, Ossenbrink J, Hoffman V. Technology life-cycles in the energy sector – technological characteristics and the role of deployment for innovation. Technol Forecast Soc Chang. 2016;104:102–21.

International Energy Agency (IEA). Ensuring green growth in a time of economic crisis: the role of energy technology. Siracusa: IEA; 2009.

Jacobsson S, Bergek A. Innovation system analyses and sustainability transitions: contributions and suggestions for research. Environ Innov Soc Transit. 2011;1:41–57.

Kirby P, O’Mahony T. The political economy of the low-carbon transition. Pathways beyond techno-optimism. London: Palgrave McMillan; 2018.

Kivimaa P, Kern F. Creative destruction or mere niche support? Innovation policy mixes for sustainability transitions. Res Policy. 2016;45(1):205–17.

Larson AL. Sustainable innovation through an entrepreneurship lens. Bus Strateg Environ. 2000;9:304–17.

Lehmann P, Söderholm P. Can technology-specific deployment policies be cost-effective? The case of renewable energy support schemes. Environ Resour Econ. 2018;71:475–505.

Levin RC, Klevoriek AK, Nelson RR, Winter SG. Appropriating the returns from industrial research and development. Brook Pap Econ Act. 1987;3:783–820.

Markard J, Raven R, Truffer B. Sustainability transitions: an emerging field of research and its prospects. Res Policy. 2012;41:955–67.

Megwai G, Njie NI, Richards T. Exploring green economy strategies and policies in developing countries. Int J Green Econ. 2016;10(3/4):338–57.

Moberg Å, Finnveden G, Johansson J, Lind P. Life cycle assessment of energy from solid waste – part 2: landfilling compared to other treatment methods. J Clean Prod. 2005;13(3):231–40.

Neuhoff K. Large-scale deployment of renewables for electricity generation. Oxf Rev Econ Policy. 2005;21(1):88–110.

Newell P. Globalization and the environment: capitalism, ecology and power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2012.

Newell P, Paterson M. Climate capitalism: global warming and the transformation of the global economy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2010.

Nicolli F, Johnstone N, Söderholm P. Resolving failures in recycling markets: the role of technological innovation. Environ Econ Policy Stud. 2012;14(3):261–88.

Organization of Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Sustainable manufacturing and eco-innovation. Framework, practices and measurement. Paris: OECD; 2009.

Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). Interim report of the green growth strategy: implementing our commitment for a sustainable future. Paris: OECD; 2010.

Popp D, Newell R. Where does energy R&D come from? Examining crowding out from energy R&D? Energy Econ. 2012;34(4):980–91.

Rodrik D. Green industrial policy. Oxford Rev Econ Policy. 2014;30(3):469–91.

Rogge KS, Reichardt K. Policy mixes for sustainability transitions: an extended concept and framework for analysis. Res Policy. 2016;45(8):1620–35.

Söderholm P, Hellsmark H, Frishammar J, Hansson J, Mossberg J, Sandström A. Technological development for sustainability: the role of network management in the innovation policy mix. Technol Forecast Soc Chang. 2019;138:309–23.

Stein JC. Efficient capital markets, inefficient firms: a model of myopic corporate behavior. Q J Econ. 1989;104:655–69.

United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP). Towards a green economy: pathways to sustainable development and poverty eradication. Nairobi: United Nations; 2011.

United Nations Environment Programme (UNEP). A guidance manual for green economy policy assessment. New York: United Nations; 2014.

United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC). 2016 biennial assess-ment and overview of climate finance flows report. Bonn: United Nations; 2016.

Unruh GC. Understanding carbon lock-in. Energy Policy. 2000;28(12):817–30.

Van Ewijk S, Stegemann JA. Limitations of the waste hierarchy for achieving absolute reductions in material throughput. J Clean Prod. 2016;132:122–8.

Walls M, Palmer K. Upstream pollution, downstream waste disposal, and the design of comprehensive environmental policies. J Environ Econ Manag. 2001;41:94–108.

Williamson O. Credible commitments: using hostages to support exchange. Am Econ Rev. 1983;73:519–40.

Download references

Acknowledgements

Financial support from Nordforsk (the NOWAGG project) is gratefully acknowledged, as are valuable comments on earlier versions of the manuscript from Åsa Ericson, Johan Frishammar, Jamil Khan, Annica Kronsell, one anonymous reviewer and the Editor. Any remaining errors, however, reside solely with the author.

Financial support from Nordforsk and the NOWAGG project on Nordic green growth strategies is gratefully acknowledged. Open access funding provided by Lulea University of Technology.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Economics Unit, Luleå University of Technology, Luleå, Sweden

Patrik Söderholm

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

Single-authored article. The author(s) read and approved the final manuscript.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Patrik Söderholm .

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval and consent to participate, consent for publication, competing interests.

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Additional information

Publisher’s note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made. The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article's Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article's Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder. To view a copy of this licence, visit http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ .

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Söderholm, P. The green economy transition: the challenges of technological change for sustainability. Sustain Earth 3 , 6 (2020). https://doi.org/10.1186/s42055-020-00029-y

Download citation

Received : 24 July 2019

Accepted : 05 January 2020

Published : 22 June 2020

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s42055-020-00029-y

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Green economy
  • Technological development
  • Radical innovation, green capitalism
  • Environmental policy
  • Policy mixes
  • Distributional effects

Sustainable Earth Reviews

ISSN: 2520-8748

  • Submission enquiries: Access here and click Contact Us
  • General enquiries: [email protected]

green economy essay

This website uses cookies

We use cookies to enable functionality, increase security and analyse site traffic to help us improve our service.

You are using an outdated browser. Please upgrade your browser to improve your experience and security.

The 5 Principles of Green Economy

Exploring what a green and fair economy looks like in principle - and in practice

5 Principles Together

Humanity faces serious challenges in the coming decades: climate change, biodiversity loss, growing inequality, and more. These systemic global crises cannot be tackled in isolation, because they are all interconnected. But our economic systems are not fit enough to deliver a good balance of environmental and social goals

Economies are, at heart, a collection of rules and norms that reward some behaviours and punish others. In their current form, our economies incentivise overconsumption, degrade communal bonds, and destroy natural wealth. But this is not inevitable or unavoidable; it is simply how our economies have evolved to operate. To solve these problems, a new economic vision is required.

The vision: a fair, green economic future

Our vision of a green economy is one that provides prosperity for all within the ecological limits of the planet. It follows five key principles, each of which draws on important precedents in international policy, and which together can guide economic reform in diverse contexts.

Wellbeing Small Rgb Pos

1. The Wellbeing Principle

A green economy enables all people to create and enjoy prosperity .

  • The green economy is people-centred . Its purpose is to create genuine, shared prosperity.
  • It focuses on growing wealth that will support wellbeing. This wealth is not merely financial, but includes the full range of human, social, physical and natural capitals.
  • It prioritizes investment and access to the sustainable natural systems, infrastructure, knowledge and education needed for all people to prosper.
  • It offers opportunities for green and decent livelihoods, enterprises and job s.
  • It is built on collective action for public goods, yet is based on individual choices

Justice Small Rgb Pos

2. The Justice Principle

The green economy promotes equity within and between generations .

  • The green economy is inclusive and non-discriminatory. It shares decision-making, benefits and costs fairly; avoids elite capture; and especially supports women’s empowerment .
  • It promotes the equitable distribution of opportunity and outcome , reducing disparities between people, while also giving sufficient space for wildlife and wilderness.
  • It takes a long-term perspective on the economy, creating wealth and resilience that serve the interests of future citizens , while also acting urgently to tackle today’s multi-dimensional poverty and injustice.
  • It is based on solidarity and social justice , strengthening trust and social ties, and supporting human rights, the rights of workers, indigenous peoples and minorities, and the right to sustainable development.
  • It promotes empowerment of MSMEs, social enterprises, and sustainable livelihoods.
  • It seeks a fast and fair transition and covers its costs – leaving no-one behind, enabling vulnerable groups to be agents of transition, and innovating in social protection and reskilling.

Planetary Boundaries Small Rgb Pos

3. The Planetary Boundaries Principle

The green economy safeguards, restores and invests in nature.

  • An inclusive green economy recognizes and nurtures nature’s diverse values – functional values of providing goods and services that underpin the economy, nature’s cultural values that underpin societies, and nature’s ecological values that underpin all of life itself.
  • It acknowledges the limited substitutability of natural capital with other capitals, employing the precautionary principle to avoid loss of critical natural capital and breaching ecological limits.
  • It invests in protecting, growing and restoring biodiversity, soil, water, air, and natural systems.
  • It is innovative in managing natural systems, informed by their properties such as circularity, and aligning with local community livelihoods based on biodiversity and natural systems.

Sufficiency Small Rgb Pos

4. The Efficiency and Sufficiency Principle

The green economy is geared to support sustainable consumption and production.

  • An inclusive green economy is low-carbon, resource-conserving, diverse and circular. It embraces new models of economic development that address the challenge of creating prosperity within planetary boundaries.
  • It recognises there must be a significant global shift to limit consumption of natural resources to physically sustainable levels if we are to remain within planetary boundaries.
  • It recognizes a ‘social floor’ of basic goods and services consumption that is essential to meet people’s wellbeing and dignity, as well as unacceptable ‘peaks’ of consumption.
  • It aligns prices, subsidies and incentives with true costs to society , through mechanisms where the ‘polluter pays’ and/or where benefits accrue to those who deliver inclusive green outcomes.

Governance Small Rgb Pos

5. The Good Governance Principle

The green economy is guided by integrated, accountable and resilient institutions.

  • An inclusive green economy is evidence-based – its norms and institutions are interdisciplinary, deploying both sound science and economics along with local knowledge for adaptive strategy.
  • It is supported by institutions that are integrated, collaborative and coherent – horizontally across sectors and vertically across governance levels – and with adequate capacity to meet their respective roles in effective, efficient and accountable ways
  • It requires public participation , prior informed consent, transparency, social dialogue, democratic accountability, and freedom from vested interests in all institutions – public, private and civil society – so that enlightened leadership is complemented by societal demand.
  • It promotes devolved decision-making for local economies and management of natural systems while maintaining strong common, centralized standards, procedures, and compliance systems.
  • It builds a financial system with the purpose of delivering wellbeing and sustainability, set up in ways that safely serve the interests of society.

The green economy is a universal and transformative change to the global status quo. It will require a fundamental shift in government priorities. Realising this change is not easy, but it is necessary if we are ever to achieve the Sustainable Development Goals.

  • Coalition News
  • The Big Picture

Related Articles

Sagar Rana 311637

Delivering on the Pact for the Future

A Call for Action submitted by the Global Research and Action Network for a New Eco-Social Contract (GRAN-ESC)

Mathias reding yf Xhq AW5 X0c unsplash

New York, New York... Here we go!

We're headed to NYC for the Summit of the Future, Action Days, the UN General Assembly, and New York Climate Week - see you there!

UNHQ with SDGs

Join us in New York at the UN Summit of the Future

We're hosting an after-summit gathering to review and strategise towards building collective action for economic systems change in 2025

Green Economy Briefing Papers

Related topics, employment, decent work for all and social protection, green economy, health and population.

green economy essay

Green Entrepreneurship and Innovation in the Circular Economy: Opportunities for Startups and Small Businesses

11 Pages Posted: 16 Sep 2024

Kazeem Adekunle

Texas A&M University Central Texas

Date Written: July 01, 2024

This paper explores the intersection of green entrepreneurship and innovation within the circular economy framework, focusing on opportunities for startups and small businesses. The circular economy presents a paradigm shift from the traditional linear economic model, emphasizing resource efficiency, waste reduction, and environmental sustainability. Green entrepreneurship emerges as a crucial driver in this transition, offering innovative solutions to environmental challenges while creating economic value. The study examines how green entrepreneurship aligns with circular economy principles and identifies key factors that enable its growth, including regulatory support, access to resources, and collaborative ecosystems. The paper highlights unique opportunities for startups and small businesses in areas such as product lifecycle management, resource recovery, circular supply chains, renewable energy, digital technologies, and consumer engagement. Through case studies of successful green businesses, the research demonstrates the practical application of circular economy principles in various sectors. The findings suggest that green entrepreneurship not only contributes to environmental sustainability but also offers significant economic potential in the evolving circular economy landscape. This study provides valuable insights for entrepreneurs, policymakers, and researchers seeking to understand and capitalize on the opportunities presented by the circular economy transition.

Keywords: Green Enterpreneurship, Circular Economy, Sustainable Innovation, Resource Efficiency, Eco-friendly Startups

JEL Classification: Q56, L26, O35, Q55, M13

Suggested Citation: Suggested Citation

Kazeem Adekunle (Contact Author)

Texas a&m university central texas ( email ), do you have a job opening that you would like to promote on ssrn, paper statistics, related ejournals, sustainable technology ejournal.

Subscribe to this fee journal for more curated articles on this topic

Waste eJournal

Urban & regional resilience ejournal, environmental, social & governance (esg) research hub ejournal.

Subscribe to this free journal for more curated articles on this topic

Environmental Data Analysis eJournal

Environmental pollution & prevention ejournal, environmental engineering & technology ejournal.

  • DOI: 10.1051/E3SCONF/202124410041
  • Corpus ID: 234299291

Social entrepreneurship in Saint-Petersburg as green economy aspect

  • O. Ignatjeva , A. Pletnev
  • Published in E3S Web of Conferences 2021
  • Environmental Science, Economics, Business, Sociology

Figures and Tables from this paper

figure 1

One Citation

Perception of social entrepreneurship competence in university business students, 47 references, the role of government and key non-state actors in social entrepreneurship: a systematic literature review, the world of the social entrepreneur, higher education for social entrepreneurship in the quadruple helix framework: co-construction in open innovation, human capital and ai in industry 4.0. convergence and divergence in social entrepreneurship in russia, social innovation and social entrepreneurship: discovering origins, exploring current and future trends, social entrepreneurship – a new look at the people and the potential, social enterprises as hybrid organizations: a review and research agenda, the manifestation of entrepreneurial orientation in the social entrepreneurship context, social entrepreneurship: towards conceptualisation, research in social entrepreneurship: past contributions and future opportunities, related papers.

Showing 1 through 3 of 0 Related Papers

  • News, Stories & Speeches
  • Get Involved
  • Structure and leadership
  • Committee of Permanent Representatives
  • UN Environment Assembly
  • Funding and partnerships
  • Policies and strategies
  • Evaluation Office
  • Secretariats and Conventions
  • Asia and the Pacific
  • Latin America and the Caribbean
  • New York Office
  • North America
  • Climate action
  • Nature action
  • Chemicals and pollution action
  • Digital Transformations
  • Disasters and conflicts
  • Environment under review
  • Environmental law and governance
  • Extractives
  • Fresh Water

Green economy

  • Ocean, seas and coasts
  • Resource efficiency
  • Sustainable Development Goals
  • Youth, education and environment
  • Publications & data

green economy essay

  • Explore Topics

green economy essay

We promote the transition to economies that are low carbon, resource efficient and socially inclusive.

If current trends continue, the global per capita use of natural resources will increase by 70 per cent by 2050..

Infrastructure

Sustainable Infrastructure Investment

Finance for Nature: Equitable, Net Zero and Positive

State of Finance for Nature

image

Economic and Trade Policy

Frutas

Advisory services

UNEP Environment & Trade Hub

Environment & Trade Hub

image

Green Growth Knowledge Platform

green economy essay

Partnership for Action on Green Economy

Photo of sunlight through clouds

Finance Industry

green economy essay

UN Environment Inquiry

green economy essay

Pathways to sustainable development and poverty eradication

News and stories.

Market products

Latin America and the Caribbean launch first regional eco-labeling programme

A sunken building surrounded by solar panels

Why making buildings greener is crucial to countering climate change

A monkey in a tree peers into the camera.

With nature in crisis, more companies are embracing safeguards to protect the planet

The press

UNEP’s Emissions Gap Report: INDCs signal unprecedented momentum for climate agreement in Paris

green economy essay

© 2024 UNEP Terms of Use Privacy   Report Project Concern Report Scam Contact Us

OECD and G20

The G20 (Group of 20) is the premier forum for global economic co-operation. It brings together leaders and policymakers from the world’s major economies to discuss key economic, development and social issues. G20 members represent around 80% of global GDP, 75% of global exports and 60% of the global population. 

Select a language

The oecd and g20.

The OECD has been a trusted strategic advisor to the G20 since the 2009 Pittsburgh Summit. The OECD Secretary-General and the OECD Sherpa participate in the G20 Leaders’ Summit and Finance Ministers and Central Bank Governors’ meetings, while the OECD Chief Economist represents the OECD at Finance Deputies’ meetings.

At the invitation of G20 Presidencies, the OECD provides substantive and strategic support to G20 workstreams in both the Sherpa and Finance Tracks. Our evidence-based analysis, data, standards, and tools have informed G20 action on shared challenges, from tackling climate change and seeking to ensure the ethical use of AI, to strengthening the global tax system and supporting sustainable development. The OECD’s contributions, which are often jointly delivered in partnership with other International Organisations, include analytical reports, monitoring of G20 commitments, and inputs on specific policy outcomes. The OECD has helped bring innovative approaches and standards to the G20 playbook, such as the OECD/G20 Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (BEPS) Project , the G20 AI Principles , and the OECD Anti-Bribery Convention .

OECD work with the 2024 G20 Presidency

The OECD is working with Brazil’s 2024 G20 Presidency to support its three objectives: (i) social inclusion and the fight against hunger and poverty; (ii) energy transitions and the promotion of sustainable development in its economic, social, and environmental dimensions; and (iii) reform of global governance institutions. We are also fully engaged in Brazil’s flagship G20 Task Force for the Establishment of a Global Alliance Against Hunger and Poverty, and its G20 Task Force for a Global Mobilisation Against Climate Change.

The OECD is supporting the Brazilian 2024 G20 Presidency’s priorities through its contributions to G20 Working Group discussions in the Sherpa and Finance Tracks.

In the Sherpa Track, we are providing evidence on diverse issues, including development, trade and investment, labour, education, gender equality, health and anti-corruption. As the 2030 Agenda faces significant hurdles to financing and stakeholder mobilisation, the OECD’s engagement across G20 Working Groups is helping advance dialogue across numerous axes of sustainable development and harnessing the G20’s potential to foster consensus and share best practices across its members. For example, we are collaborating closely with Brazil’s Development Cooperation Agency in the Development Working Group to catalyse triangular co-operation to build trust-based partnerships, leveraging our expertise to support anti-corruption measures to achieve sustainable development, and using data from our Teaching and Learning International Survey to advance Brazil’s efforts in building teacher capacity.

In the Finance Track, the OECD is contributing its work on blended finance for sustainable development, financial markets, tax transparency and effective tax administration. This work is informing the G20’s dialogue on strategic macroeconomic issues, supporting a stronger global financial system, and helping align all finance flows with the SDGs. The OECD is also helping advance Brazil’s objective to reform global governance institutions, particularly  Multilateral Development Banks (MDBs) and their capacity to drive transformative development.  

Previous G20 Presidencies

  • India's 2023 G20 Presidency The OECD helped shape the narrative around the Indian Presidency’s development and climate agendas. Key contributions included an OECD report on bottlenecks to development finance to inform an update of the G20 Action Plan on Accelerating Progress Towards the SDGs, as well as support for India's Lifestyle for Environment Initiative (LiFE) through OECD evidence on financing green transitions, demand side measures, the circular economy, and resource efficiency. The OECD also contributed to other key priorities of India’s Presidency. For example, on digitalisation, we supported the development of a G20 Common Framework with High-Level Principles to enhance the digital security of products and services, and also informed discussions on digital skills. In the Finance Track, the OECD’s contributions included work on sustainable finance and implementation of the Two-Pillar Solution, as well as the revised G20/OECD Principles of Corporate Governance. Learn more
  • Indonesia's 2022 G20 Presidency The OECD informed the Indonesian Presidency's discussions on the global recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic and exit strategies from the economic downturn. This included supporting dialogue between G20 Health and Finance Ministers through the Joint Finance-Health Task Force (JFHTF), which was launched at the end of Italy’s 2021 G20 Presidency. The OECD contributed to the G20’s development agenda through a report on blended finance, and also helped to draft the G20 Principles on Scaling-up Private and Blended Finance in Developing Countries, LDCs, and SIDS. Our work on blended finance informed the G20 Bali Compact, a compendium of clean energy principles. Learn more
  • Italy's 2021 G20 Presidency The Italian Presidency sought to ensure a swift international response to the COVID-19 pandemic. OECD support included analysis on the impact of the COVID-19 pandemic on the SDGs, as well as on measures to strengthen medical supply chains and the global health workforce. In partnership with the ILO, the OECD analysed the impact of COVID-19 on education and global labour markets. Learn more

St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulu’s Hypothesis (with diagram)

green economy essay

Daniel Bernoulli evinced great interest in the problem known as St. Petersburg paradox and tried to resolve this. St. Petersburg paradox refers to the problem why most people are unwilling to participate in a fair game or bet.

For example, offer of participating in a gamble in which a person has even chance (that is, 50-50 odds) of winning or losing Rs. 1000 is a fair game.

To put in mathematical terms, a gamble whose expected value is zero, or more generally, the game in which the fee for the right to play is equal to its expected value is a fair one. Thus, according to St. Petersburg in an uncertain game a most individuals will not make a fair bet or, in other words, will not play the fair game.

Daniel Bernoulli provided a convincing explanation of the said behaviour of rational individual. According to him, a rational individual will take decisions under risky and uncertain situations on the basis of expected utility rather than expected monetary value.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

He further contended that marginal utility of money to the individual declines as he has more of it. Since the individual behaves on the basis of expected utility from the extra money if he wins a game and the marginal utility of money to him declines as he has extra money, most individuals will not ‘play the game’, that is, will not make a bet. It is in this way that Bernoulli resolved ‘St. Petersburg paradox’.

A graphic illustration will make clear Bernoulli’s solution to the paradox. Consider Figure 17.1 in which on the X-axis, the quantity of money (thousands of rupees) and on the Y-axis, marginal utility of money (rupees) to an individual are measured. Suppose an individual has 20 thousands of rupees with him and can make a bet at even odd (i.e., 50-50 chance) of winning or losing rupees one thousand.

If he wins the bet, money with him will rise to 21 thousand (20 + 1) rupees. If as a result of an increase in money with him, his expected marginal utility of money declines, then the expected marginal utility of extra one thousand rupees to him which is depicted by the rectangle CDFE is less than the extra marginal utility of the previous one thousand (i.e., 20th thousand) rupees which is measured by the rectangle ABDC.

In other words, the gain in utility in case of his winning the bet is less than the loss of utility in case of his losing the bet, though the gain and loss is the same in terms of monetary amount (i.e., Rs. one thousand). Thus, given the diminishing marginal utility of money the expected gain in utility is less than the expected loss of utility from one thousand rupees involved in the bet, a rational individual will therefore not make a bet with 50-50 odds.

Bernoulli's Hypothesis: Unwillingness to Participate in a Fair Game

In case he wins the bet, his monetary gain will be Rs. 1500 which will raise his money income to Rs. 21,500 and gain in his total utility will be given by the black-shaded area and if he loses the bet, his income falls by Rs. 1000 to Rs. 19,000 and as a result he suffers a loss in total utility equal to the red-shaded area.

It will be observed from Figure 17.2 that despite a smaller loss in money terms, the loss in terms of total utility is greater than the gain in total utility despite a greater increase in money in case he wins the bet. This happened due to the rapid decline in marginal utility of money as individual’s money increases.

Unwillingness to Participate at Favourable when MU of Money declines Rapidly

It may be pointed out that in our discussion aboveabout the individual’s betting it is assumed that individual derives no pleasure from gambling, that is, he does not enjoy gambling for its own sake. This is another way of saying that the individual behaves rationally in the sense that he will behave on the basis of expected gains and losses of utility from winning and losing money through gambling.

Although Bernoulli’s hypothesis that individual decision to participate in a gamble or not, depends on his expected utility rather than expected money value of the game is of crucial significance in any discussion of individual’s behaviour under risky and uncertain situations. So long as there is no upper bound on the utility function, the prize in a gamble can be appropriately adjusted so that the paradox is regenerated. Further Bernoulli’s main point that an individual considers expected utility from the extra money rather than monetary value of the gain itself has found wide acceptance among economists.

However, a major drawback of Bernoulli’s expected utility hypothesis is that it assumes cardinally measurable utility which economists today find it difficult to believe. J. Von Neumann and O. Morgenstern adopted an entirely new approach to assigning numerical values to the utilities obtained from extra money by the individuals behaving in risky or uncertain situations, such as in case of gambling and insurance and they based their method of constructing utility index (which is envied at in a different way from the cardinal measurement of utility by neoclassical economists) on the expected utility hypothesis of Bernoulli. They showed that we can analyse the choice by an individual under risky and uncertain situation on the basis of N – M utility index.

Neumann-Morgenstern Utility Concept Index under Risky Situations:

Making use of Bernoulli’s idea that under risky and uncertain prospects as in betting, gambling and purchasing lottery tickets etc., a rational individual will go by the expected utilities rather than expected money values, Neumann and Morgenstern in their now famous work ” Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour gave a method of numerically measuring expected utility from winning prizes. On the basis of such utility index, called N-M index rational decisions are made by the individuals in case of risky situations.

Thus, Neumann- Morgenstern method seeks to assign a utility number or in other words, construct N-M utility index of the total utility of money which a person gets as his stock of money wealth increases. The choices by an individual under risky and uncertain situations depend on N-M utility index (i.e. expected numerical utilities) and with changes in money income.

Related Articles:

  • Utility Theory and Attitude toward Risk (Explained With Diagram)
  • Risk Aversion and Insurance (Explained With Diagram)
  • Risk Preference and Gambung: Why Do Some Individuals Gamble?
  • Preference Hypothesis and Strong Ordering (Explained With Diagram)

IMAGES

  1. The Growing Opportunities of the Green Economy Free Essay Example

    green economy essay

  2. ⇉Review of the Green Economy Today Essay Example

    green economy essay

  3. Green Economy: being sustainable is a big business!

    green economy essay

  4. The Green Economy: Characteristics, Principles and Importance

    green economy essay

  5. Green Economy and Sustainability

    green economy essay

  6. (PDF) TOWARDS A GREEN ECONOMY From ideas to practice

    green economy essay

COMMENTS

  1. About green economy

    An inclusive green economy is one that improves human well-being and builds social equity while reducing environmental risks and scarcities. An inclusive green economy is an alternative to today's dominant economic model, which exacerbates inequalities, encourages waste, triggers resource scarcities, and generates widespread threats to the environment and human health.

  2. PDF The Case for a Green Economy

    A green economy is one that promotes both sustainability and economic growth. It is a viable alternative to today's dominant economic model, which exacerbates inequalities, promotes waste, causes resource scarcity, and poses widespread threats to the environment and human health. The transition to a green economy can be accomplished in a ...

  3. Essay On Green Economy

    Essay On Green Economy. 1351 Words6 Pages. Green growth and green economy have been subject to various definitions but those currently being used by international organizations have a lot in common. Greening growth (GG) and moving towards a greener economy (GE) is complex and multidimensional.

  4. PDF A guidebook to the Green Economy

    The strategy has three overall objectives, (1) to promote eco‐friendly new growth engines for the national economy, (2) to enhance the quality of life for the members of the society, and (3) to contribute to the international efforts to fight climate change.

  5. Green economy

    A green economy is an economy that aims at reducing environmental risks and ecological scarcities, and that aims for sustainable development without degrading the environment. [1] [2] [3] It is closely related with ecological economics, but has a more politically applied focus.[4] [5] The 2011 UNEP Green Economy Report argues "that to be green, an economy must not only be efficient, but also fair.

  6. Green economy: a path towards development and poverty eradication

    Ecology, economy, and equity. Those are the key points in a Green Economy. Those are the pathway to a wealthy and inclusive nation. For the past few years, the use of term "Green Economy" has increased and has e.g. been used by the UN, heads of state, the EU, and OECD to explain the nexus between sustainability, economics and the environment.

  7. Why does green economy matter?

    An inclusive green economy is one that improves human well-being and builds social equity while reducing environmental risks and scarcities. An inclusive green economy is an alternative to today's dominant economic model, which exacerbates inequalities, encourages waste, triggers resource scarcities, and generates widespread threats to the environment and human health.

  8. Green Economy and Sustainability

    Green economy is often viewed as the alternative to the current approach towards consumption. Traditionally, green economy is defined as the attempt of developing the economic strategy that will allow for a reasonable allocation of natural resources and the practice of sustainability. Emerging in 1990s and gaining significance in 2000s, the ...

  9. PDF The Transition to a Green Economy: Benefits, Challenges to

    green economy initiatives as part of the stimulus packages being put in place to support the recovery. Furthermore, when the GA decided to call a UN Conference on Sustainable ... Responding to concerns of many countries, the three papers underscore that the concept of green economy should be seen as consistent with the broader and older concept of

  10. (PDF) Towards a New, Green Economy

    A further premise of this essay is that the principal goal of the green economy is to deliver prosperity. In other words, the green economy must deliver the capabilities for individuals to ...

  11. The green economy transition: the challenges of technological change

    The Green Economy is an alternative vision for growth and development; one that can generate economic development and improvements in people's lives in ways consistent with advancing also environmental and social well-being. One significant component of a green economy strategy is to promote the development and adoption of sustainable technologies. The overall objective of this article is to ...

  12. PDF Towards a economyy GREEN

    nable economic progress. In our modelling of a green investment scenario channelling capital amounting to 2% of global GDP (US$ 1,300 billion) to embark on a green economic transformation, one-quarter of this amount - 0.5% of GDP (US$ 325 billion) - is allocated to natural capital sectors: forestry, agricultur.

  13. Transition to a green economy: benefits, challenges and risks ...

    This document responds to this mandate. It contains three papers. The first one, by José Antonio Ocampo, looks at the macroeconomic policy implications of the transition to the green economy. The second, by Aaron Cosbey, focuses on the interlinked issues of trade, investment and technology. The third, by Martin Khor, considers the risks that this concept generates for developing countries and ...

  14. The 5 Principles of Green Economy

    1. The Wellbeing Principle. A green economy enables all people to create and enjoy prosperity. The green economy is people-centred. Its purpose is to create genuine, shared prosperity. It focuses on growing wealth that will support wellbeing. This wealth is not merely financial, but includes the full range of human, social, physical and natural ...

  15. PDF Conclusions

    Towards a green economy This report marks a first step in outlining key issues for moving towards a green economy at a national and global level. In summary, it has found that a green economy values and invests in natural capital. Ecosystem services are better conserved, leading to improved safety nets and household incomes for poor rural ...

  16. PDF A Guidebook to the Green Economy

    United Nations A guide to the green economy: Issue 4 - 2 - Acknowledgement The information in this paper was compiled by the United Nations Division for Sustainable

  17. Interpreting the green economy: Emerging discourses and their

    2. Green economy origins. Although the concept of a 'green economy' was first introduced by Pearce et al. (Citation 1989), it was not until the global financial crisis of 2008, which coincided with heightened recognition of deepening environmental and social crises, that the concept moved into mainstream policy discourse.At the time, the United Nations General Assembly and other UN ...

  18. The geography of green innovation hubs in OECD regions

    This paper explores the geography of "green innovation hubs" and the relationship between green patents and local labour markets. The analysis considers the spatial distribution and evolution of patenting activity for green inventions and identifies green innovation hubs, i.e., regions demonstrating notable strength in green patenting. It also explores the relationship between the regional ...

  19. Green Economy Briefing Papers

    Under its Green Economy Initiative, UNEP prepared a series of nine green economy briefing papers on priority issues for the transformation towards a green economy: poverty reduction; advisory services; health; indicators; trade; finance; employment; valuing nature; and innovation. Each brief provides an overview of the issue, the way forward, and outlines what UNEP is doing to address the issue.

  20. Green Economy

    A green economy is defined as low carbon, resource efficient and socially inclusive. In a green economy, growth in employment and income are driven by public and private investment into such economic activities, infrastructure and assets that allow reduced carbon emissions and pollution, enhanced energy and resource efficiency, and prevention of the loss of biodiversity and ecosystem services.

  21. Green Entrepreneurship and Innovation in the Circular Economy ...

    Green entrepreneurship emerges as a crucial driver in this transition, offering innovative solutions to environmental challenges while creating economic value. The study examines how green entrepreneurship aligns with circular economy principles and identifies key factors that enable its growth, including regulatory support, access to resources ...

  22. [PDF] Social entrepreneurship in Saint-Petersburg as green economy

    Identification of the prospects for the social entrepreneurship expansion as one of the aspects of green economy uses the example of St. Petersburg. We use a statistical method for processing nominal data with the aid of SPSS. The study revealed that social-oriented not-for-profit organizations and government social agencies work with the same social groups and offer similar services.

  23. Efforts to promote green economic development

    Vietnam is striving to promote the development of a green economy across all sectors, but to advance further on this journey, it is necessary to swiftly complete a comprehensive and clear green taxonomy. Vietnam is striving to promote the development of a green economy across all sectors - Illustrative Photo.

  24. Green economy

    Pathways to sustainable development and poverty eradication. If current trends continue, the global per capita use of natural resources will increase by 70 per cent by 2050. We promote the transition to economies that are low carbon, resource efficient and socially inclusive.

  25. OECD and G20

    The G20 (Group of 20) is the premier forum for global economic co-operation. It brings together leaders and policymakers from the world's major economies to discuss key economic, development and social issues. G20 members represent around 80% of global GDP, 75% of global exports and 60% of the global population.

  26. St. Petersburg Paradox and Bernoulu's Hypothesis (with diagram)

    Daniel Bernoulli evinced great interest in the problem known as St. Petersburg paradox and tried to resolve this. St. Petersburg paradox refers to the problem why most people are unwilling to participate in a fair game or bet. For example, offer of participating in a gamble in which a person has even chance (that is, 50-50 odds) of winning or losing Rs. 1000 is a fair game. To put in ...